3 Quantitative Results

In this section we cover the foundations of quantitative finance. For a more detailed treatment, I recommend the following execellent texts:

Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives by John C. Hull

Derivative Markets by Robert L. McDonald

3.1 Arbitrage

An arbitrage is a risk-less profit that requires no initial investment. One of the basic tenets of quantitative finance is that arbitrage opportunities should not exist in the markets. The reasoning is as follows: if an arbitrage exists, market participants will pile onto the trade, thus moving prices until the arb no longer available.

Much of theoretical quantitative finance consists of theorems which are proved by using arbitrage arguements. These theorems often involve questionable assumptions about the market, and can be of little to use to finance practitioners.

There is, however, a strong kernel of truth in arbitrage arguments. If markets significantly breach so-called no arbitrage prices, then there will be safe and profitable trades in the market. Traders will eventually catch on to the these trades, which will cause prices to move toward the no-arbitrage levels.

Keep your eyes peeled for arbs in the market. And if you find one, please call me.

3.2 Stocks & Dividends

Companies can raise funds to grow their business by issuing shares of stock. The buyer of the stock, called a shareholder, pays money to the company which the company keeps forever. In return, the shareholder is entitled to a fraction of the companies future profits and also has the ability to vote on certain matters at shareholder meetings. A crucial point is that the owner of a stock has limited liability with respect to the company. The worst thing that can happen is that shareholder never receives any profits, and the stock itself also becomes worthless. So, for example, if the company is caught illegally polluting, the shareholder cannot be sued for damages. In this sense the value of stock can never be negative.

Once a stock has been issued by a company, the owner of the stock can sell it to another investor. This is called a secondary market transaction. Once the share has been sold in the secondary market, the claims to profits and the voting rights are both transferred to the new owner.

Secondary market transactions occur on exchanges such as the New York Stock Exchange. The secondary markets are usually what people are referring to when they talk about the stock market. These transactions occur via complicated auction mechanisms that match buyers and sellers. The mechanisms are such that the actual trade prices can fluctuate (sometimes greatly) from one transaction to the next.

Here are some examples of companies who’s stocks trade heavily in the secondary markets.

AAPL - Apple

GOOG - Alphabet

FB - Facebook

XOM - Exxon Mobile

Suppose you want to trade a share of stock, and you want to be able to fill your order immediately. If you are a buyer of the stock, you will be charged a certain amount called the ask price. If you are a seller of the stock you will receive a certain amount called the bid price. The bid price is lower than the ask price. These so-called bid-ask spreads exist in other financial markets as well, including options markets.

If you are a market participant for a particular stock, there are at least three different prices that you will need to be aware of. The current bid price, the current ask price, and the last price at which a trade occurred.

Through out the course of this book, we will often refer to the price of a stock at time \(t\), and denote it with something like \(S_{t}\). In doing so, we will be referring to one of the following:

  1. The current mid price, which is as the average of the bid and ask at time \(t\).

  2. The last trade price as of time \(t\).

For stocks that have high trading volume, these two values will be usually quite close - but this is not always the case.

Options markets are far less liquid than stock markets. This means that there are larger bid-ask spreads, and longer spans of time between trades. For these reasons, in options markets it is important to clarify what is meant by the phrase the price at time t.

The upshot of our previous discussion about exchanges is that \(S_{t}\) varies through time. As it turns out, it is useful to think of the of \(S_{t}\) as a series of random variable. In math circles this is know as a stochastic process.

When profits are distributed to the owners of a stock, this is done on a per share basis. The amount that is paid per share is called a dividend payment. It is reasonable to wonder whether issuing a dividend payment has any near-term impact on the price of the stock. As it turns out it does, and this question leads to our first quantitative result involving an arbitrage argument.

Theorem: Suppose that a stock is going make a divided payment of \(c\) at time \(T\) and that just prior to the dividend payment is trading at a price of \(S^{*}\). Then then price of the stock just after the dividend payment is \(S_{T} = S^{*} - c\).

Proof: NEED TO FILL IN.

Rigorously defining the concept of a share of stock is a complicated legal exercise, and a precise account of how stocks are bought and sold in the secondary market would require its own large book. The amount of detail you will ultimately need know depends on how you intend to apply your knowledge. For example, if you are an attorney that works on IPOs, you will need to know a lot about the legal stuff. If you are a creating statistical arbitrage strategies, you will need be an expert on exchange microstructure.

For the purposes of this book, the following stylized facts will suffice.

  1. A shareholder purchases stock which gives them claims to a company’s future profits. This is a limited liability investment in that the value of a stock can never be negative.

  2. After their initial issuance, shares of stock can be bought and sold in the secondary market.

  3. Trading of stocks on the secondary market occurs on exchanges, with trades occurring thousands or millions of times a day during business hours.

  4. The exchange creates complex auction mechanisms to match buyers and sellers. The rules of these auctions are such that trades can occur at different prices for every transaction. Trade prices can vary greatly from transaction to transaction.

  5. The stream of trade prices is often denoted as \(S_{t}\) can be conceptualized as a stochastic process.

  6. Profits are paid out to shareholders in the form of a per-share payment called a dividend. Immediately after the payment of a dividend, the stock price will reduce by the amount of the dividend.

3.3 Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs)

Investing in stocks and other assets is usually an overly costly and complex endeavor for an individual. For this reason, there are various vehicles for small investors to pool their money and for it to be invested as a single fund. The most common form of investment pooling is a mutual fund. More esoteric manifestations are hedge funds, unit investment trust (UIT), and real estate investment trusts (REIT). The distinction between these is of general interest, but won’t be of huge importance to us in this book.

A fairly recent innovation in the world of pooled investments is exchange traded funds (ETFs). Relative to mutual funds and hedge funds, ETFs engage in simpler strategies that are easier to execute. For this reason, it take fewer people to manage the fund and costs are low. In addition, shares of ETF ownership are traded on exchanges in the exact same way as shares of stock. ETFs pay dividends in the same way that stocks do. Here are some popular ETFs:

SPY - SPDR SP500 - tracks the S&P500.

IWM - iShares Russell 2000.

GLD - invests in gold futures.

XLF - SPDR Financial - tracks the performance of financial services sector.

In this book we will consider options who’s underlyings are stocks and ETFs. We will treat these two underlyings as largely the same.

3.4 Discounting & Accumulating

When you lend money, you are paid interest to compensate for the fact that you can’t use the lent funds for other purposes. In this book we assume that loans are totally safe in that there is no risk of default.

It is useful to conceptualize payment of interest as an accumulation over time. We will use the following notation and nomenclature to capture this idea of accumulation:

Definition: Assume the current time is \(t\) and that \(T\) is some time in the future. Then one dollar will accumulate to \(A(t,T)\) by time \(T\). We will call \(A(t,T)\) an accumulation factor.

If you are going to receive money in the future, it’s not really worth as much to you as if the money were paid right now. The way we account for this value difference is by discounting by the amount of interest you could have earned between now when you are going to be paid. This is the notion of present value. We express it as follows:

Definition: Let \(t\) be some time before time \(T\). The time \(t\) present value of a one dollar cash flow at time \(T\), will be denoted by \(D(t,T)\). We call \(D(t,T)\) a discount factor.

The following statements are true:

  1. \(A(t,T) \geq 1\).

  2. \(D(t, T) \leq 1\).

  3. \(D(t,T) = A(t,T)^{-1}\).

Definition: Suppose the current time is \(t\). Consider a series of cash flows \(C_{1}, \ldots, C_{n}\) occurring at future times \(t_{1}, \ldots, t_{n}\). Then the time \(t\) present value of this stream of cash flows is defined as:

\[\begin{align*} PV(\{ C_{1}, \ldots, C_{n} \}) = \sum_{i = 1}^{n} D(t, t_{i}) \cdot C_{i}. \end{align*}\]

Forward Accumulating

Suppose that the current time is \(t\) and that \(T\) is some time in the (distant) future. Suppose that for all times \(s\) between \(t\) and \(T\), we know the values \(A(t,s)\). This set of accumulation factors is known as the spot yield curve (it is usually quoted as interest rates, but the idea is the same).

Now, suppose for some future time \(t^*\) you want to work out an arrangement with your bank such that you will deposit one dollar at time \(t^*\) and let it accumulate until \(T\). What is the accumulation factor that you should earn? Do you have to wait until time \(t^*\) to find out, or can you lock one in now.

It turns out that this forward accumulation factor is determined by the spot yield curve. We will denote the quantity \(A(t, t^*, T)\), and we have that:

\[\begin{align*} A(t, T) = A(t, t^*) \cdot A(t, t^*, T) \end{align*}\]

Proof:

3.5 Option Contracts

We discussed vanilla (American and European) options at length in the previous chapter. We discuss them here again more formally.

NEED TO FINISH

3.6 Forward Contracts

Forward contracts are simple derivatives that are one of the foundational building blocks of quantitative finance. The value of forwards are related to option prices via a result known as put-call parity, a finding that is seminal to much of derivatives theory.

3.6.1 Specification and Payoff

A forward contract is the obligation to transact some underlying asset at some future date. The transaction occurs at a fixed price, called the strike price. The party that agrees to buy the underlying is called the long side. The party that agrees to sell the underlying is the short side. The underlyings we will consider in this book will be stocks or ETFs, but forwards can exist on any kind of underlying: gold, corn, etc.

The key feature of a forward is that both sides are obligated to execute their side of the transaction - to either buy our sell the asset, at the agreed upon strike price. This stands in contrast to an option, in which the long side has a right, while the short side has an obligation.

Consider a forward contract struck at \(K\) expiring at time \(T\). Suppose that underlying is trading at \(S_{T}\) at the time of expiration. The long side has agreed to pay \(K\), and in return receives the underlying which has a value of \(S_{T}\). Thus the long position is worth \(S_{T} - K\) at expiration. On the other hand, the short side receives \(K\) but has to deliver the underlying, which is worth \(S_{T}\). So the short position is worth \(K - S_{T}\).

Long Payoff: \(S_{T} - K\)

Short Payoff: \(S_{T} - K\)

3.6.2 The Forward Price

Suppose that the current time is \(t\) and that we are considering a forward contract that expires at time \(T\). Suppose further that the underlying is currently trading at \(S_{t}\). We are interested in the following question: is there strike price of \(K\) such that both parties can enter into the forward contract for zero cost, without introducing an arbitrage opportunity for either side?

It turns out the answer is yes, an this strike price is of such importance that it has been named simply, the forward price. The forward price is determined by two points in time: the current time \(t\) and the expiration time \(T\). We will denote the forward price associated with these two times as \(F(t, T)\).

Forward Pricing Formula: Suppose we are considering a forward contract at time \(t\) which expires at time \(T\). Suppose that the underlying is currently trading at \(S_{t}\) and that during the life of the forward, the underlying stock pays dividends \(c_{1}, \ldots, c_{n}\) at times \(t_{1}, \ldots, t_{n}\). Then the we have that:

\[\begin{align*} F(t, T) &= A(t, T) \cdot S_{t} - \sum_{i=1}^{n} A(t, t_{i}, T) \cdot c_{i} \end{align*}\]

Proof:

In words, we have that the forward price is the accumulated value of the current stock price less the accumulated value of all the dividend payments during the life of the contract.

Notice that for non-dividend paying stocks, the forward price is simply the accumulated value of the current stock price: \(F(t, T) = A(t, T) \cdot S_{t}\).

3.6.3 Valuing a Forward Contract

Suppose that you enter into a forward contract at time \(t^{*}\) and the strike price \(K\) was chosen such that both parties could enter into the contract for zero cost. Suppose that the time is now \(t > t^{*}\), what would be the value to unwind this contract?

Fact: The no arbitrage unwind value of this contract is \(D(t, T) \cdot (F(t, T) - K)\).

Proof:

This result really has nothing to do with the fact that the forward contract entered into at time \(t^{*}\) or that it’s initial strike what chosen to make it a zero value contract. Ultimately it just gives us a formula for valuing a forward contract at any point.

Notice that if a forward contract is struck at the current forward price, then it has zero value, which we would expect.

3.6.4 Synthetic Forwards

A portfolio consisting of a long call and a short put is a synthetic forward position. More specifically, you simultaneously hold a long call and a short put, both with the same strike \(K\), and both expiring at the same time \(T\), then your payoff at time \(T\) will be the same as a long forward contract struck at \(K\) and expiring at \(T\). Let’s see how this is the case.

Let the current time be \(t\). Consider a call and put on the same underlying, with the same strike price \(K\), that both expire at time \(T\). If you have a long position in the call and a short position in the put, then in all states of the world at time \(T\) this portfolio has a value of \(S_{T} - K\), which is the same value as the payoff as a long forward.

Suppose that \(S_{T} > K\). You exercise your long call, for which you receive the stock worth \(S_{T}\) while paying the strike price \(K\) for it. The put you are short expires worthless. The total value of these two positions is \(S_{T} - K\).

On the other hand, suppose \(S_{T} < K\). Your short put position will be exercised, forcing you to buy the stock for \(K\) even though it is only worth \(S_{T}\). Your call is worthless, so you won’t exercise. Once again, the combined value of these two position is \(S_{T} - K\).

If \(S_{T} = K\), nothing happens because both options are worthless. Doing nothing has zero value. But of course in this situation we have that \(S_{T} - K = 0\).

3.7 Put-Call Parity

Our discussion of synthetic forwards leads us to one of the most important results in all of derivatives theory: put-call parity.

Let the current time be \(t\). Consider a put and a call that both expire at time \(T\), both struck at \(K\). We know that the long call combined with the short put create a synthetic forward with strike price \(K\). From previous sections we also know how to value a forward contract. Putting these two results together we get following put-call parity identity:

\[\begin{align*} C(t, T, K) - P(t, T, K) = D(t, T) \cdot (F(t, T) - K). \end{align*}\]

Let’s examine a couple special cases more closely.

Non-Dividend Paying Stock

Recall that when the stock pays no dividends during the life of the forward, that the forward price is simply the accumulated spot price. Thus, we have

\[\begin{align*} C(t, T, K) - P(t, T, K) &= D(t, T) \cdot (F(t, T) - K) \\ &= D(t, T) \cdot (A(t, T) \cdot S_{t} - K) \\ &= S_{t} - D(t, T) \cdot K. \end{align*}\]

Dividend Paying Stock

Suppose that during the life of the options the underlying stock pays dividends of \(c_{1}, \ldots, c_{n}\) at times \(t_{1}, \ldots, t_{n}\). Then we have that

\[\begin{align*} C(t, T, K) - P(t, T, K) &= D(t, T) \cdot (F(t, T) - K) \\ &= D(t, T) \cdot \bigg(A(t, T) \cdot S_{t} - \sum_{i=1}^{n} A(t, t_{i}, T) \cdot c_{i} - K \bigg) \\ &= S_{t} - PV(\{c_{1}, \ldots, c_{n} \}) - D(t, T) \cdot K. \end{align*}\]

3.8 Rational Option Pricing

The Black-Scholes pricing framework, which we will discuss at length in later chapters, requires complex assumptions about the random nature of the underlying, and dynamic trading strategies for replicating option payoffs. These complexities are required to give a specific value of to an option. But there is a actually a lot we can say about option prices without making any assumptions of the underlying. This line of reasoning is called rational option pricing.

Not only does rational pricing yield practically useful results, understanding these arguments helps to build intuition about options.

Extreme American Bounds

Our first results place crude bounds on the price of options.

The worst thing that can happen with either a long put or long call position, is that it is not exercised. So vanilla options can never have negative value.

As a call buyer, the best outcome is that you exercise, which results in owning the stock Thus, call can never be worth more than the underlying stock. As a put buyer, the best outcome is that you exercise when the stock is worthless, and you receive \(K\). Thus, the put can never be worth more that \(K\).

These facts are summarized in the following inequalities:

\[\begin{align*} 0 &\leq C_A(S, K, T) \leq S \\ 0 &\leq P_A(S, K, T) \leq K. \end{align*}\]

Americans \(\geq\) European

Any strategy that you can execute with a European option, you can execute with the American variant as well. Thus, American are worth at least as much as their European equivalents. This is summarize with the following inequalities:

\[\begin{align*} C_E(S, K, T) &\geq C_A(S, K, T) \\ P_E(S, K, T) &\geq C_A(S, K, T). \end{align*}\]

Call Bounds

We can string together put-call parity along with the previous two results (add equation numbers), to arrive at the following series of inequalities:

\[\begin{align*} \text{max}\big\{ 0, D(t, T) \cdot ((F(t, T) - K)) \big\} \leq C_E(S, K, T) \leq C_A(S, K, T) \leq S. \end{align*}\]

From left to right, the justification for these three are as follows:

  1. Extreme lower bound combined with put-call parity. Notice that this is equivalent to saying that a vanilla call is always worth more than it’s intrinsic value.

  2. Americans are worth more than Europeans.

  3. Extreme upper bound for Americans.

Put Bounds

We can argue for a similar sequence of inequalities for puts:

\[\begin{align*} \text{max}\big\{ 0, D(t, T) \cdot (K - F(t, T)) \big\} \leq P_E(S, K, T) \leq P_A(S, K, T) \leq K. \end{align*}\]

Here is the justification:

  1. Extreme lower bound combined with put-call parity. Notice that this is equivalent to saying that a vanilla put is always worth more than intrinic.

  2. Americans are worth more than Europeans.

  3. Extreme upper bound for Americans.

Early Exercise No Dividends

It is never optimal to early exercise an American call option on a non-dividend paying stock. For a non-dividend paying underlying, it is always better to sell the call than to exercise. To see this, recall that from put call parity we have that

\[\begin{align*} C_E(S_t, K T) &= D(t, T) \cdot (F(t, T) - K) + P_E(K, T) \\ &= D(t, T) \cdot (A(t, T) \cdot S_t - K)) + P_E(S_t, K, T) \\ &= S_t - D(t, T) \cdot K + P_E(S_t, K, T). \end{align*}\] If we can show that \(S_t - D(t, T) \cdot K + P_E(K, T) > S_t - K\) then we are done, because American options are always worth at least as much as Europeans. This inequality is equivalent to \[\begin{align*} K > D(t, T) \cdot K - P_E(S_t, K, T) \iff \\ K\cdot(1 - D(t, T)) + P_E(S_t, K, T) > 0 \end{align*}\]

But of course this final inequality is true because \(D(t, T) < 1\) and \(P_E(S_t, K, T) > 0\).

Early Exercise Single Dividend

(NOT COMPLETE) Consider and American call on a stock that pays a single dividend, call it \(\delta\), before the option expires, say at time \(t^*\). From put-call parity we have \[\begin{align*} C_E(S_t, K, T) &= D(t, T) \cdot (F(t, T) - K) + P_E(S_t, K, T) \\ &= D(t, T) \cdot (A(t, T) \cdot S_t - D(t, t^*)\delta - K) + P(S_t, K, t) \\ &= S_t - D(t, T) \cdot D(t, t^*) \delta - K \cdot D(t, T) + P(S_t, K, t) \end{align*}\]